The Energy Collective

The world's best thinkers on energy and climate

  • Home
  • Post Here
  • Columns
    • Electricity Markets & Policy Group
    • Full Spectrum
    • Energy and Policy Developments
    • Game Changers
    • Energy for Human Development
    • Seeking Consensus
    • Green Growth
    • New Energy Voices
  • Fuels
    • Oil
    • Wind
    • Nuclear Power
    • Coal
    • Natural Gas
    • Solar Power
    • Renewables
    • Biofuels
    • Geothermal Energy
    • Wave & Tidal
    • Hydro Power
  • Environment
    • Carbon and De-carbonization
    • International Climate Conferences
    • Sustainability
    • Climate
    • Public Health
    • Water
    • Recycling
  • Grid
    • Smart Grid
    • Electricity
  • Tech
    • Cleantech
    • Green Building
    • Storage
    • Rare Earth Minerals
  • Business and Economy
    • Cap-and-Trade
    • Agriculture
    • Efficiency
    • Green Business
    • Utilities
    • Finance
    • Green Jobs
    • Subsidies
    • Risk Management
  • Politics
    • Environmental Policy
    • Energy Security
    • Communications and Messaging
    • China
  • Transport
  • Help
    • FAQ
  • Account
    • Login
    • Register

A Pragmatic Proposal for Supplier Compensation

September 21, 2017 by Philip Baker

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

KiWi Power smart grid center.

The European Commission has proposed that independent aggregators should not be required anymore to pay compensation to suppliers, as is the case in many EU member states today. According to Philip Baker of the Regulatory Assistance Project (RAP) this proposal should be supported, as it will improve the flexibility of the market and lead to lower prices for consumers. However, it may not be appropriate in the long term: once it has achieved its goals, the issue of compensation should be revisited. (Editor’s note: this article is part of a two-part debate on supplier compensation in the EU power market. See for a different view this article from Kristian Ruby, Secretary-General of Eurelectric.)

Explicit demand response is a process in which third-party aggregators pay domestic and smaller commercial customers to flex their demand. It provides these consumers with a low-risk, automated path to market participation. It also helps to ease the integration of intermittent wind and solar generation, and reduce or delay the need for network investment associated with electrifying the heat and transport sectors.

In addition to smoothing the transition to a low-carbon future, explicit demand response can deliver an immediate and beneficial impact on customer’s electricity bills. By reducing demand during periods when capacity is scarce and wholesale prices are high, demand response reduces overall market costs thereby benefiting all consumers in the form of lower electricity bills, not just those who participate. Analysis suggests that even a modest application of demand response could generate savings of up to €1.6 billion annually across the German/Austrian, Nordic, and French electricity markets alone, with greater savings expected across Europe as a whole.

However, despite these benefits and the need to encourage customers to be more flexible, significant barriers to the successful development of aggregated demand response exist. In many Member States, aggregators are required to obtain permission from the customer’s supplier to operate on a customer’s load and to compensate the supplier for lost income. These requirements undermine the already fragile economics of explicit demand response, particularly in the domestic sector, and should be removed.

The Commission’s pragmatic proposals

The European Commission has proposed, in Article 17 of the Clean Energy Package Electricity Directive, which it presented on 30 November 2016, that aggregators should no longer be required seek permission from a customer’s supplier and that they should not be required to pay compensation to suppliers. This proposal is very much to be welcomed. While aggregators do not need to recover fuel costs, they do face significant capital costs in setting up explicit demand response programs, operating costs, and also need to pay participating customers. Given present market conditions, where highly restrictive price caps are often applied, forcing aggregators to compensate suppliers directly would undermine the economics of aggregation and significantly constrain its development.

The Commission’s proposal is a pragmatic response to this situation. It promotes the development of aggregation to ensure that allconsumers have the opportunity to share in the associated benefits, while recognising that suppliers have the option of “self-compensating,” i.e., retaining some of reduction in wholesale prices before passing the remaining benefits on to consumers in the form of lower retail rates.

Anticipating the impact of wholesale market reform

The response to the Commission’s proposal has been mixed. The proposals are clearly helpful to the aggregator community, however suppliers are understandably concerned about not being able to recover the cost of energy that they may have bought up-front, but which they cannot bill to consumers who have opted not to consume that energy.

These concerns are not without justification. While the proposal that aggregators should not be required to compensate suppliers is appropriate in the prevailing circumstances, this may not be the case going forward. The Commission’s welcome proposals for wholesale market reform set out in the Clean package will, once implemented, substantially raise or remove price caps and ensure that wholesale energy prices more closely reflect the value that customers place on uninterrupted supply. Aggregated demand response will clearly benefit from periods of higher and more volatile energy prices, and market reform should significantly improve its profitability.

Therefore, once market reform has been introduced and aggregators, acting on behalf of customers, can access wholesale prices that reflect the true value of the demand response services they provide, it will become appropriate to revisit the issue of compensation. At that point, the question will become what level of compensation is appropriate?

Compensation set too low could over-stimulate demand response, at some point resulting in costs to non-participating consumers that exceed the benefits; compensation set too high could reward uneconomic behaviour by suppliers and suppress cost-effective demand-side resources. Given that the timing and extent of market reform will vary across jurisdictions, determining when to revisit the issue of compensation and what compensation should apply, are decisions best left to individual Member States.

A suggested amendment to the Commission’s proposal

Therefore, in order ensure that the Commission’s proposals for supplier compensation are consistent with the other market reforms called for by the Clean Energy Package, we suggest that a sunset clause should be applied to the current wording of Article 17 paragraph 3d of the Electricity Directive, which says that aggregators shall not be required to pay compensation to suppliers or generators. This would allow Member States to revisit the issue of compensation once market reform had been fully implemented or, alternatively, when it was considered that aggregated demand response was sufficiently developed or its economics sufficiently robust.

Once either of these two criteria has been satisfied, the goal of maximizing economic efficiency seems best achieved by linking compensation to the average year-ahead or seasonal wholesale energy price. This should both approximate the purchasing costs incurred by competent suppliers while rewarding aggregators and their customers roughly in line with the net benefits that price-responsive demand would realize. This approach has the added benefit of striking a fair balance between suppliers’ legitimate interest in being compensated and the intractable question of determining exactly what costs were incurred in any given case.

An additional safeguard to ensure the appropriate but not excessive deployment of aggregated demand response might be to include a net benefits test. This would compare the benefits of aggregated demand response seen by customers in the form of reduced wholesale energy prices with the market revenues seen by aggregators. If the latter exceeded the former, this would suggest that the introduction of direct aggregator to supplier compensation was justified. This would to some extent mirror the arrangements introduced by FERC (Federal Energy Regulatory Commission) in the United States, where explicit demand response is also subject to a cost benefit test.

In conclusion, we believe that Commission’s stance that aggregators should not be required to compensate suppliers directly is appropriate, given prevailing market conditions. But once the wholesale market has been reformed in line with the Commission’s proposals set out in the Clean Energy Package, demand response will become a far more profitable enterprise, so compensation should be allowed again.

Philip Baker responds to the article by Kristian Ruby of Eurelectric, “Stimulating demand response by forbidding supplier compensation is neither fair nor efficient“:

Eurelectric suggest that the Commission’s proposal would allow aggregators to re-sell energy without paying for it.  In fact, aggregators don’t sell energy as such, they offer a reduction in energy to the market. If accepted, these offers reduce the amount of energy consumed and, as no more energy can be generated than is consumed, reduce the amount of energy that needs to be generated.

Eurelectric also suggest that the benefits of demand response accrue exclusively to the aggregator.  Again, this is not accurate as demand response will reduce wholesale market clearing prices, therefore benefiting all suppliers who buy energy in the market and, ultimately, consumers – assuming that suppliers pass on these price reductions via retail tariffs.  Demand response therefore benefits allconsumers, not just those who reduce demand.

Finally, Eurelectric suggest that the Commission’s proposal could lead to the risk of demand response being “over-used” to the detriment of consumers.  However, this risk is easily addressed by applying a “net benefit” test as suggested by RAP, similar to that applied in the United States.

Editor’s Note

The Regulatory Assistance Project (RAP) is a globally operating independent and nonpartisan team of experts. Philip Baker (pbaker@raponline.org) is an energy consultant working with RAP and other clients on power system technical and commercial issues, integrating renewable energy sources, and European electricity market integration.

Original Post

Related posts:

Energy News: Cities Going All In; Water Heaters Storing Energy for the Grid Cheap Renewables Are Transforming the Global Electricity Business Snow, Cold Temperatures Offer No Proof of Need for Coal, Nuclear Subsidies Lessons Learned from New York REV: A Roadmap to Reduce Emissions Through Utility Reform

Philip Baker

Philip Baker (pbaker@raponline.org) is an energy consultant working with RAP and other clients on power system technical and commercial issues, integrating renewable energy sources, and European electricity market integration.

Filed Under: Cleantech, Communications and Messaging, Efficiency, Electricity, Electricity Grid, Energy, Energy and Economy, Energy Security, Environment, Finance, Fuels, Green Business, News, Politics & Legislation, Renewables, Risk Management, Smart Grid, Storage, Subsidies, Sustainability, Tech, Utilities Tagged With: energy management, energy planning, europe, european commission, renewables integration, supplier compensation

  Subscribe  
newest oldest most voted
Notify of
Bentvels
Member
Bentvels
September 24, 2017 13:24

Third-party aggregators only exist because utilities were too inflexible, not customer directed enough.
There is no places in the future electricity market of such rigid suppliers.

With the advent of smart metering for consumers, it becomes very easy for utilities to offer demand response services to consumers.
Introducing electricity tariffs such as the day ahead intra-day whole sale prices + a surcharge. So the consumer can adapt his consumption.

0
 |   -   Share         Hide Replies ∧

The Energy Collective Columns

Full Spectrum: Energy Analysis and Commentary with Jesse JenkinsEnergy and Policy Developments with John Miller
Game Changers column badgeEnergy for Human Development Column
Seeking Consensus with Schalk CloeteGreen Growth with Silvio Marcacci
New Energy VoicesMore coming soon...

Latest comments

  • Bas Gresnigt on Why Nuclear Fusion is Gaining Steam – Again Thanks for your interesting background story. Yet the Energiewende scenario developed gradually d (April 19, 2018 at 11:32 AM)
  • Bas Gresnigt on Why Nuclear Fusion is Gaining Steam – Again Mark, Your Berkeley study states that solar needs 76 times more and wind needs 10 times more materia (April 19, 2018 at 11:14 AM)
  • Bas Gresnigt on Why Nuclear Fusion is Gaining Steam – Again EP, The software of the wind turbines can be adapted such that they cut out gradually and each at d (April 19, 2018 at 10:01 AM)
  • Bas Gresnigt on Why Nuclear Fusion is Gaining Steam – Again Mark, Wind is hardly curtailed. It is used to pump water in the upper reservoir of their pumped st (April 19, 2018 at 9:31 AM)

Advisory Panel

About the panel

Scott Edward Anderson is a consultant, blogger, and media commentator who blogs at The Green Skeptic. More »


Christine Hertzog is a consultant, author, and a professional explainer focused on Smart Grid. More »


Elias Hinckley is a strategic advisor on energy finance and energy policy to investors, energy companies and governments More »


Gary Hunt Gary is an Executive-in-Residence at Deloitte Investments with extensive experience in the energy & utility industries. More »


Jesse Jenkins is a graduate student and researcher at MIT with expertise in energy technology, policy, and innovation. More »


Jim Pierobon helps trade associations/NGOs, government agencies and companies communicate about cleaner energy solutions. More »


Geoffrey Styles is Managing Director of GSW Strategy Group, LLC and an award-winning blogger. More »


Featured Contributors

Rod Adams

Scott Edward Anderson

Charles Barton

Barry Brook

Steven Cohen

Dick DeBlasio

Senator Pete Domenici

Simon Donner

Big Gav

Michael Giberson

Kirsty Gogan

James Greenberger

Lou Grinzo

Jesse Grossman

Tyler Hamilton

Christine Hertzog

David Hone

Gary Hunt

Jesse Jenkins

Sonita Lontoh

Rebecca Lutzy

Jesse Parent

Jim Pierobon

Vicky Portwain

Willem Post

Tom Raftery

Joseph Romm

Robert Stavins

Robert Stowe

Geoffrey Styles

Alex Trembath

Gernot Wagner

Dan Yurman

 

 

 

Follow Us

32-linkedin 32-facebook 32-twitter 32-rss

Content for personal use only. Distribution prohibited. Republication in part or in whole is strictly prohibited. © All rights reserved Energy Central © 2018

Recent Comments

  • Bas Gresnigt on Why Nuclear Fusion is Gaining Steam – Again
  • Bas Gresnigt on Why Nuclear Fusion is Gaining Steam – Again
  • Bas Gresnigt on Why Nuclear Fusion is Gaining Steam – Again

Recent Posts

  • New Solar Capacity Exceeded All Other Fuel Sources Combined in 2017, Study Finds
  • Fine-Tuning Fusion
  • U.S. and Canadian Nuclear Labs Announce Programs to Support Developers and Supply Chains for Small Modular and Advanced Reactors

Useful Pages

  • Terms of Use
  • Comments Policy
  • Privacy & Cookies
  • Help
  • About and Contact Us
Copyright © 2018 Energy Central. All Rights Reserved
This site uses cookies, for a number of reasons. By continuing to use this website you accept the use of cookies. Find out more.